How
about quantitative easing for the people?
Anatole
Kaletsky
1
August, 2012
Through
an almost astrological coincidence of timing, the European Central
Bank, the Bank of England and the U.S. Federal Reserve Board all held
their policy meetings this week immediately after Wednesday’s
publication of the weakest manufacturing numbers for Europe and
America since the summer of 2009. With the euro-zone and Britain
clearly back in deep recession and the U.S. apparently on the brink,
the central bankers all decided to do nothing, at least for the
moment. They all restated their unbreakable resolution to do
“whatever it takes” – to prevent a breakup of the euro, in the
case of the ECB, or, for the Fed and the BoE, to achieve the more
limited goal of economic recovery. But what exactly is there left for
the central bankers to do?
They
have essentially two options. They could do even more of what the Fed
and the BoE have been doing since late 2008 – creating new money
and spending it on government bonds, in the policy known as
“Quantitative Easing.” Or they could admit the policies of the
past three years were not working, at least not well enough. And try
something different.
There
is, admittedly, a third option – to do nothing, on the grounds that
public bodies should stop interfering with the private economy and
instead leave financial markets to restore economic prosperity and
full employment of their own accord. This third idea is based on the
economic theory that if governments and central bankers leave well
enough alone, “efficient” and “rational” financial markets
will keep a capitalist economy growing and automatically return it to
a prosperous equilibrium after occasional hiccups. This theory,
though still taught in graduate schools and embedded in economic
models, is implausible, to put it mildly, especially after the
experience of the past decade. In any case, experience shows that the
option of government doing nothing in deep economic slumps simply
doesn’t exist in modern democracies.
Returning,
therefore, to the two realistic alternatives, central bankers and
financiers are overwhelmingly in favor of the first: keep trying the
policy that has failed.
While
QE might still help in the euro zone, since the ECB is the only
entity that can guarantee that Italy, Spain and France will not go
into a Greek-style default, the U.S. and British situations are very
different. The U.S. and British governments control their own
currencies and therefore face no risk of default. What, then, would
be the benefit of more QE in the U.S. or Britain?
So
far $2 trillion has been created by the Fed and £375 billion by the
Bank of England, but where has all this new money gone? It has
certainly not appeared in my wallet or bank account – nor has it
fattened yours, unless you happen to be a bond trader or banker. The
fact is that all the new money has been spent on buying bonds. QE has
thus inflated bond prices and boosted bank profits, but achieved
little else.
The
one economic benefit of QE has been to help governments finance the
huge deficits caused by recession without having to raise taxes,
slash public spending or face Greek-style bankruptcy. In this sense,
QE has certainly prevented the U.S. and Britain from suffering worse
outcomes, but it has failed to stimulate employment or economic
growth. This is exactly what Japan has experienced for 20 years –
and as in Japan, additional rounds of QE now will merely act as an
anesthetic, perpetuating stagnation but discouraging more effective
stimulus measures.
One
such radical measure is too controversial for any policymaker to
mention publicly, although some have discussed it in private: Instead
of giving newly created money to bond traders, central banks could
distribute it directly to the public. Technically such cash handouts
could be described as tax rebates or citizens’ dividends, and they
would contribute to government deficits in national accounting. But
these accounting deficits would not increase national debt burdens,
since they would be financed by issuing new money, at zero cost to
government or to future generations, instead of selling
interest-bearing government bonds.
Giving
away free money may sound too good to be true or wildly
irresponsible, but it is exactly what the Fed and the BoE have been
doing for bond traders and bankers since 2009. Directing QE to the
general public would not only be much fairer but also more effective.
Suppose
the new money created since 2009, instead of propping up bond prices,
had simply been added to the bank accounts of all U.S. and British
households. In the U.S., $2 trillion of QE could have financed a cash
windfall of $6,500 for every man, woman and child, or $26,000 for a
family of four. Britain’s QE of £375 billion is worth £6,000 per
head or £24,000 per family. Even if only half the new money created
were distributed in this way, these sums would be easily large enough
to transform economic conditions, whether the people receiving these
windfalls decided to spend them on extra consumption or save them and
reduce debts.
Distributing
money to the general public was the one response to intractable
recessions and liquidity traps that united Milton Friedman and John
Maynard Keynes. Their main difference was that Friedman proposed
dropping dollar bills out of helicopters, while Keynes suggested
burying pound notes in chests that unemployed workers could dig up.
Unfortunately modern economics, based as it is on simplistic and
misleading assumptions about self-stabilizing markets, has forgotten
the insights of these great students of deep economic slumps. In
today’s world of electronic money, we would not even need
Friedman’s helicopters or Keynes’s ditchdiggers. Just a few lines
of computer code – plus some imagination and courage from our
central banks.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.