Losing
our AAA rating could mean bank collapse and deflation
Like
a condemned man, the British government awaits the sentence. It’s
ceased to be a question of whether we’ll lose our AAA rating, but
when.
20
February, 2013
In
the City, traders have started to ask each other nervously: “Could
it be this evening? Have you heard anything?”
If
the UK economy shrinking by 0.3pc at the end of 2012 wasn’t quite
enough to kill off our AAA, the expected confirmation in next month’s
Budget that the underlying 2012-13 deficit will be higher than the
2011-12 deficit may be. Even one-off factors aren’t going George
Osborne’s way. The Autumn Statement allowed for £3.5bn in receipts
from the sale of 4G mobile phone licences, and the Treasury expected
to get more. On Wednesday, it turned out the sale yielded only
£2.3bn.
At
the 2010 General Election, Mr Osborne’s key “benchmark” against
which “the public can judge the success or failure of their
Chancellor and their Government over the next Parliament” was to
“cut the deficit more quickly to safeguard Britain’s credit
rating”. Losing the AAA rating would thus clearly be a political
humiliation for the Chancellor.
But
would it matter economically? Many commentators have started
suggesting not. They note that after the US and France were
downgraded, government bond yields did not spike up in the way they
did when Ireland and Greece suffered the same fate, but instead
actually fell — markets reacted to downgrades in the US and France
by buying more government bonds, not fewer. Anyway, they ask, aren’t
ratings agencies discredited by having failed to downgrade various
assets early enough during the credit crisis?
And
if the AAA is gone anyway, they say, we might as well be hanged for a
sheep as a lamb and borrow more — in this very newspaper we have
seen schemes for embracing the AAA loss to spend more on
infrastructure or cut tax.
Now,
of course, the key thing isn’t the AAA as such, but the underlying
situation of which the AAA is just an indicator. But that underlying
situation does matter, and the blasé attitude that both the US and
France survived downgrades, so why shouldn’t we, is frankly
dangerous.
We
can think of government bond yields — the interest rate that the
Government has to pay to borrow money — as dependent upon three
things. First, the risk that the Government might default. Second,
the growth prospects for the economy as a whole. Third, the
quantitative easing (QE) programme of the Bank of England.
It’s
obvious why the risk of default matters — higher default risk means
a higher interest rate to compensate. The growth prospects for the
economy as a whole matter because if people are willing to buy
government bonds at a given yield, that must mean they don’t expect
to get a better yield elsewhere, such as in shares or machines. If
the yield on government bonds is very low, as it has been in the UK
for the past couple of years, yet people are still buying government
bonds, that must mean the expected return on all other assets is low
as well. But if the expected return on all assets (all business
assets, say) is low, that means the economy can be expected to grow
only very slowly.
The
third factor is QE. Most of it has been used to buy government bonds,
bidding up the price and hence bidding down the yield, making
interest rates low. That has probably reduced government bond yields
by more than 1.5 percentage points. If more QE is expected, yields
may fall further.
When
a country is downgraded, the consequences for government interest
rates depend on the interplay of these factors. A small downgrade,
such as that of the US or France, indicates only a slight increase in
the risk the country defaults, but might also indicate that growth
prospects are weak and might trigger policy-makers to respond by
printing extra money. If financial markets interpret a downgrade as
materially damaging growth prospects and likely to trigger more QE,
but only meaning a slight increase in default risk, they will react
by buying more government bonds, so yields will fall.
Hence
it should be no surprise that in the US and France, after their
downgrades, yields fell. But that doesn’t mean those downgrades (or
the underlying situation that triggered them) didn’t matter. A
downgrade triggering a yields drop is a bad thing — it means growth
prospects declining.
The
one thing worse than a downgrade leading to yields dropping is a
downgrade leading to them spiking, and there is no guarantee that for
the UK the reaction would be the former. UK growth prospects are
already terrible, and our banks are much more extended than US ones,
while British households are more indebted than those in France.
Furthermore, the AAA rating is central to the UK’s international
reputation as a finance centre.
If
our growth prospects deteriorate even further, then without even
higher inflation, UK households will default on their mortgages,
bankrupting British banks and thereby bankrupting the Government if
it stands behind the banks. We have already seen that happen in
Ireland and Spain. It could happen here, too.
Banks
in this country are doubly exposed, because regulators have forced
them to hold vast amounts of UK government debt. Even relatively
modest rises in government bond yields, implying some fall in
government bond prices, would impose huge losses on UK banks. The
Bank of England has suggested that UK banks already need £60bn of
extra capital. Taking large losses on UK government bonds could push
them over the edge.
Falls
in UK government bond prices would also mean huge losses for the
Treasury via the QE programme. The original intention to unwind QE
gradually as coupons were paid and bonds matured has recently been
abandoned — the programme can now be unwound only by actively
selling bonds, which would surely trigger a huge yield spike and
losses for banks and the government of up to half their bond
holdings.
On
Wednesday, the Bank of England minutes revealed that the last
Monetary Policy Committee meeting voted only by 6-3 against doing
even more QE, despite inflation being expected to be above target for
years. One factor affecting thinking is surely the consequences of
losing the AAA. Perhaps more QE might buy more government bonds.
Perhaps they might just buy bank bonds directly. Either way,
policymakers are showing signs of desperation.
Following
the AAA loss, the ways forward may be bank collapse and deflation, or
even more QE and even more inflation. It’s not a happy choice.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.