Jim Grant Warns America's Default Is Inevitable
Authored
by James Grant (of Grant's
Interest Rate Observer),
originally posted at The
Washington Post,
11
October, 2013
“There
is precedent for a government shutdown,”
Lloyd Blankfein, the chief executive officer of Goldman Sachs,
remarked last week. “There’s no precedent for default.”
How
wrong he is.
The
U.S. government defaulted after the Revolutionary War, and it
defaulted at intervals thereafter. Moreover,
on the authority of the chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, the
government means to keep right on shirking, dodging or trimming, if
not legally defaulting.
Default
means to not pay as promised, and politics may interrupt the timely
service of the government’s debts. The
consequences of such a disruption could — as everyone knows by now
— set Wall Street on its ear. But after the various branches of
government resume talking and investors have collected themselves,
the Treasury will have no trouble finding the necessary billions with
which to pay its bills. The Federal Reserve can materialize the scrip
on a computer screen.
Things
were very different when America owed the kind of dollars that
couldn’t just be whistled into existence. By
1790, the new republic was in arrears on $11,710,000 in foreign debt.
These were obligations payable in gold and silver. Alexander
Hamilton, the first secretary of the Treasury, duly paid them. In
doing so, he cured a default.
Hamilton’s
dollar was defined as a little less than 1/20 of an ounce of gold. So
were those of his successors, all the way up to the administration of
Franklin D. Roosevelt. But in the whirlwind of the “first hundred
days” of the New Deal, the dollar came in for redefinition. The
country needed a cheaper and more abundant currency, FDR said. By and
by, the dollar’s value was reduced to 1/35 of an ounce of gold.
By
any fair definition, this was another default. Creditors
both domestic and foreign had lent dollars weighing just what the
Founders had said they should weigh. They expected to be repaid in
identical money.
Language
to this effect — a “gold clause” — was standard in debt
contracts of the time, including instruments binding the Treasury.
But Congress resolved to abrogate those contracts, and in 1935 the
Supreme Court upheld Congress.
The
“American default,” as this piece of domestic stimulus was known
in foreign parts , provoked condemnation in the City of London. “One
of the most egregious defaults in history,” judged the London
Financial News. “For repudiation of the gold clause is nothing less
than that. The plea that recent developments have created abnormal
circumstances is wholly irrelevant. It was precisely against such
circumstances that the gold clause was designed to safeguard
bondholders.”
The
lighter Roosevelt dollar did service until 1971, when President
Richard M. Nixon lightened it again. In fact, Nixon allowed it to
float. No longer was the value of the greenback defined in law as a
particular weight of gold or silver. It became what it looked like: a
piece of paper.
Yet
the U.S. government continued to find trusting creditors. Since the
Nixon default, the public’s holdings of the federal debt have
climbed from $303 billion to $11.9 trillion.
If
today’s political impasse leads to another default, it will be a
kind of technicality. Sooner or later, the Obama Treasury will resume
writing checks. The question is what those checks will buy.
“Less
and less,” is the Federal Reserve’s announced goal. Under
Chairman Ben Bernanke (with the full support of the presumptive
chairman-to-be, Janet Yellen), the central bank has redefined price
“stability” to mean a rate of inflation of 2 percent per annum.
Any smaller rate of depreciation is an unsatisfactory showing to be
met with a faster gait of money-printing, policymakers say.
In
other words, the value of money has become an instrument of public
policy, not an honest weight or measure. In
such a setting, an old-time “default” is impossible. How can a
creditor cry foul when the government to which he is lending has
repeatedly said that the value of the money he lent will shrink?
The
post-1971 dollar derives its value from the stamp of the government
that issues it. Across
the seas, this imprimatur is starting to look a little tenuous. Lend
us your dollars for 10 years, the Treasury proposes. We will pay you
the lordly interest rate of 2.7 percent per annum. And at the end of
those 10 years, we will hand you back your principal, which will
almost certainly buy less than the money you lent.
This
is the unsustainable conceit of the world’s superpower-cum-super
debtor. By deed, if not audible word, we Americans say: “The
greenback is the world’s great monetary brand. You have no choice
but to use it. Like it or lump it.” But the historical record of
paper currencies is clear: Governments always over-issue it. The
people finally do lump it.
What
to do? Let
us face facts: We have defaulted in the past. Let us confront the
implied message of the Federal Reserve’s pro-inflation policy: We
will default in the future, though no lawyer will call it
“default.” And
let us preempt the world’s flight from our intangible money by
taking steps to fashion a 21st-century improvement. We
have the gold and the brains to find the solution.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.