Crude
oil tops $96
UPI,
22
January, 2013
The
price of crude oil topped $96 Tuesday, adding 75 cents to reach
$96.60 a barrel on the New York Mercantile Exchange.
Gasoline
gained 2.25 cents to $2.819 a gallon.
Home
heating oil low5 0.79 cents to $3.0621 a gallon.
Natural
gas lost 5.9 cents to $3.57 per million British thermal units.
At
the pump, AAA reported the national average
Ten
Reasons Why High Oil Prices are a Problem
Gail
Tverberg
17
January, 2013
A
person might think from looking at news reports that our oil problems
are gone, butoil
prices are still high.
Figure
1. US crude oil prices (based on average prices paid by US refiners
for all grades of oil based on EIA data) converted to 2012$ using
CPI-Urban data from the US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
In
fact, the new “tight oil” sources of oil which are supposed to
grow in supply are still expensive to extract. If we expect to have
more tight oil and more oil from other unconventional sources, we
need to expect to continue to have high oil prices. The new oil may
help supply somewhat,
but the high
cost of extraction is
not likely to go away.
Why
are high oil prices a problem?
1.
It is not just oil prices that rise. The
cost of food rises as well, partly because oil is used in many ways
in growing and transporting food and partly because of the
competition from biofuels for land, sending land prices up. The cost
of shipping goods of all types rises, since oil is used in nearly all
methods of transports. The cost of materials that are made from oil,
such as asphalt and chemical products, also rises.
If
the cost of oil rises, it tends to raise the cost of other fossil
fuels. The cost of natural gas extraction tends to rises, since oil
is used in natural gas drilling and in transporting water for
fracking. Because of an over-supply of natural gas in the US, its
sales price is temporarily less
than the cost of production.
This is not a sustainable situation. Higher oil costs also tend to
raise the cost of transporting coal to the destination where it is
used.
Figure
2. US Energy Prices as % of Wages and as of GDP. Ratio to GDP
provided by EIAShort
Term Economic Outlook – Figure 27,
converted to Wage Base by author, using same wages as described for
Figure 3.
Figure
2 shows total energy costs as a percentage of two different bases:
GDP and Wages.1 These
costs are still near their high point in 2008, relative to these
bases. Because oil is the largest source of energy, and the highest
priced, it represents the majority of energy costs. GDP is the usual
base of comparison, but I have chosen to show a comparison to
wages as well. I do this because even if an increase in costs takes
place in the government or business sector of the economy, most of
the higher costs will eventually have to be paid for by individuals,
through higher taxes or higher prices on goods or services.
2.
High oil prices don’t go away, except in recession.
We
extracted the easiest (and cheapest) to extract oil first. Even oil
company executives say, “The
easy oil is gone.”
The oil that is available now tends to be expensive to extract
because it is deep under the sea, or near the North Pole, or needs to
be “fracked,” or is thick like paste, and needs to be melted. We
haven’t discovered cheaper substitutes, either, even though we have
been looking for years.
In
fact, there is good reason to believe that the cost of oil extraction
will continue to rise faster than the rate of inflation, because we
are hitting a situation of “diminishing returns”. There is
evidence that world
oil production costs are increasing at about 9% per year (7%
after backing about the effect of inflation). Oil prices paid by
consumers will need to keep pace, if we expect increased extraction
to take place. There is even
evidence that
sweet sports are extracted first in Bakken tight oil, causing
the cost of this extraction to rise as well.
3.
Salaries don’t increase to offset rising oil prices.
Most
of us know from personal experience that salaries don’t rise with
rising oil prices.
In
fact, as oil prices have risen since 2000, wage growth has
increasingly lagged GDP growth. Figure 3 shows the ratio of wages
(using the same definition as in Figure 2) to GDP.
Figure
3. Wage Base (defined as sum of “Wage and Salary Disbursements”
plus “Employer Contributions for Social Insurance” plus
“Proprietors’ Income” from Table 2.1. Personal Income and its
Distribution) as Percentage of GDP, based on US Bureau of Economic
Analysis data. *2012 amounts estimated based on part-year data.
If
salaries don’t rise, and prices of many types of goods and services
do, something has to “give”. This disparity seems to be the
reason for the continuing economic discomfort experienced in the past
several years. For many consumers, the only solution is a long-term
cut back in discretionary spending.
4.
Spikes in oil prices tend to be associated with recessions.
Economist
James Hamilton has
shown that 10
out of the last 11 US recessions were associated with oil price
spikes.
When
oil prices rise, consumers tend to cut back on discretionary
spending, so as to have enough money for basics, such as food and
gasoline for commuting.
These cut-backs in spending lead to
lay-offs in discretionary sectors of the economy, such as vacation
travel and visits to restaurants. The lay-offs in these sectors
lead to more cutbacks in spending, and to more debt defaults.
5.
High oil prices don’t “recycle” well through the economy.
Theoretically,
high oil prices might lead to more employment in the oil sector, and
more purchases by these employees. In practice, this provides only a
very partial offset to higher price. The oil sector is not
a big employer, although
with rising oil extraction costs and more US drilling, it is getting
to be a larger employer. Oil importing countries find that much
of their expenditures must go abroad. Even if these expenditures are
recycled back as more US debt, this is not the same as more US
salaries. Also, the United States government is reaching debt limits.
Even
within oil exporting countries, high oil prices don’t necessarily
recycle to other citizens well. A
recent study shows that 2011 food price spikes helped trigger the
Arab Spring.
Since higher food prices are closely related to higher oil prices
(and occurred at the same time), this is an example of poor
recycling. As populations rise, the need to keep big populations
properly fed and otherwise cared for gets to be more of an issue.
Countries with high populations relative to exports, such as Iran,
Nigeria, Russia, Sudan, and Venezuela would seem to have the most
difficulty in providing needed goods to citizens.
6.
Housing prices are adversely affected by high oil prices.
If
a person is required to pay more for oil, food, and delivered
goods of all sorts, less will be left over for discretionary
spending. Buying a new home is one such type of discretionary
expenditure.
US
housing prices started to drop in mid 2006, according to data of
the S&P
Case Shiller home price index.
This timing fits in well with when oil prices began to rise, based on
Figure 1.
7.
Business profitability is adversely affected by high oil prices.
Some
businesses in discretionary sectors may close their doors completely.
Others may lay off workers to get supply and demand back into
balance.
8.
The impact of high oil prices doesn’t “go away”.
Citizens’
discretionary income is permanently lower. Businesses that close when
oil prices rise generally don’t re-open. In some cases, businesses
that close may be replaced by companies in China or India, with lower
operating costs. These lower operating costs indirectly reflect the
fact that the companies use less oil, and the fact that their workers
can be paid less, because the workers use less oil. This is a part of
the reason why US employment levels remain low, and why we don’t
see a big bounce-back in growth after the Great Recession. Figure 4
below shows the big shifts in oil consumption that have taken place.
Figure
4. Percentage growth in oil consumption between 2006 and 2011, based
on BP’s 2012 Statistical Review of World Energy.
A
major part of the “fix” for high oil prices that does takes place
is provided by the government. This takes the place in the form of
unemployment benefits, stimulus programs, and artificially low
interest rates.
Efficiency
changes may provide some mitigation, as older less fuel-efficient
cars are replaced with more fuel-efficient cars. Of course, if the
more fuel-efficient cars are more expensive, part of the savings to
consumers will be lost because of higher monthly payments for the
replacement vehicles.
9.
Government finances are especially affected by high oil prices.
With
higher unemployment rates, governments are faced with paying more
unemployment benefits and making more stimulus payments. If there
have been many debt defaults (because of more unemployment or because
of falling home prices), the government may also need to bail out
banks. At the same time, taxes collected from citizens are lower,
because of lower employment. A major reason (but not the only reason)
for today’s debt problems of the governments of large oil
importers, such as US, Japan, and much of Europe, is high oil prices.
Governments
are also affected by the high cost of replacing infrastructure that
was built when oil prices were much lower. For example, the cost of
replacing asphalt roads is much higher. So is the cost of replacing
bridges and buried underground pipelines. The only way these costs
can be reduced is by doing less–going back to gravel roads, for
example.
10.
Higher oil prices reflect a need to focus a disproportionate share of
investment and resource use inside the oil sector. This makes it
increasingly difficult maintain growth within the oil sector, and
acts to reduce growth rates outside the oil sector.
There
is a close tie between energy consumption and economic activity
because nearly all economic activity requires the use of some type of
energy besides human labor. Oil is the single largest source of
energy, and the most expensive. When we look at GDP growth for the
world, it is closely aligned with growth in oil consumption and
growth in energy consumption in general. In fact, changes in oil and
energy growth seem to precede GDP growth, as might be expected if oil
and energy use are a cause of
world economic growth.
Figure
5. Growth in World GDP, energy consumption, and oil consumption. GDP
growth is based on USDA
International Macroeconomic Data.
Oil consumption and energy consumption growth are based on BP’s
2012 Statistical Review of World Energy.
The
current situation of needing increasing amounts of resources to
extract oil is sometimes referred to one of declining Energy
Return on Energy Invested (EROEI).
Multiple problems are associated with declining EROEI, when cost
levels are already high:
(a)
It becomes increasingly difficult to keep scaling up oil industry
investment because of limits on debt availability, when heavy
investment is made up front, and returns are many years away. As an
example, Petrobas
in Brazil is
running into this limit. Some
US oil and gas producers are
reaching debt limits as well.
(b)
Greater use of oil within the industry leaves less for other sectors
of the economy. Oil production has not been rising very quickly in
recent years (Figure 6 below), so even a small increase by the
industry can reduce net availability of oil to society. Some of
this additional oil use is difficult to avoid. For example, if oil is
located in a remote area, employees frequently need to live at great
distance from the site and commute using oil-based means of
transport.
Figure
6. World crude oil production (including condensate) based primarily
on US Energy Information Administration data, with trend lines
fitted by the author.
(c)
Declining EROEI puts pressure on other limited resources as well. For
example, there can be water limits, when fracking is used, leading to
conflicts with other use, such as agricultural use of water.
Pollution can
become an increasingly large problem as
well.
(d)
High oil investment cost can be expected to slow down new investment,
and keep oil supply from rising as fast world demand rises. To the
extent that oil is necessary for economic growth, this slowdown will
tend to constrain growth in other economic sectors.
Airline
Industry as an Example of Impacts on Discretionary Industries
High
oil prices can be expected to cause discretionary sectors to shrink
back in size. In many respects, the airline industry is the “canary
in the coal mine,” showing how discretionary sectors can be forced
to shrink.
In
the case of commercial air lines, when oil prices are high, consumers
have less money to spend on vacation travel, so demand for airline
tickets falls. At the same time, the price of fuel to operate
airplanes rises, making the cost of operating airplanes higher.
Business travel is less affected, but still is affected to some
extent, because some long-distance business travel is discretionary.
Airlines
respond by consolidating and cutting back in whatever ways they can.
Salaries of pilots and stewardesses are reduced. Pension plans are
scaled back. New more fuel-efficient aircraft are purchased, and less
fuel-efficient aircraft are phased out. Less profitable routes are
closed. The industry still experiences bankruptcy after bankruptcy,
and merger after merger. If oil prices stabilize for a while, this
process stabilizes a bit, but doesn’t
really stop.
Eventually, the commercial airline industry may shrink to such an
extent that necessary business flights become difficult.
There
are many discretionary sectors besides the airline industry waiting
in the wings to shrink. While oil prices have been high
for several years, their effects have not yet been fully incorporated
into discretionary sectors. This is the case because governments have
been able to use deficit spending and artificially low interest rates
to shield consumers from the “real” impacts of high-priced oil.
Governments
are now finding that debt cannot be ramped up indefinitely. As taxes
need to be raised and benefits decreased, and as interest rates are
forced higher, consumers will again see discretionary income
squeezed. New cutbacks are likely to hit additional discretionary
sectors, such as restaurants, the “arts,” higher education, and
medicine for the elderly.
It
would be very helpful if new unconventional oil developments would
fix the problem of high-cost oil, but it is difficult to see how they
will. They are high-cost to develop and slow to ramp up. Governments
are in such poor financial condition that they need taxes from
wherever they can get them–revenue of oil and gas operators is a
likely target. To the extent that unconventional oil and gas
production does ramp up, my expectation is that it will be too
little, too late, and too high-priced.
Note:
[1]
Wages include private and government wages, proprietors’ income,
and taxes paid by employers on behalf of employees. They do not
include transfer payments, such as Social Security.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.