Master
of the elite, George Soros speaks out
As
Soros Starts A Three Month Countdown To D(oom)-Day, Europe Plans A
New Master Plan
2
June, 2012
What
would the weekend be without at least one rumor that Europe is on the
verge of fixing everything, or failing that, planning for a master
fix, OR failing
that, planning
for a master plan to
fix everything. Sure enough, we just got the latter, which
considering nobody really believes anything out of Europe anymore,
especially not something that has not been signed, stamped and
approved by Merkel herself, is rather ballsy. Nonetheless, one can't
blame them for trying: "The chiefs of four European institutions
are in the process of creating a master
plan for
the euro zone, the daily Die Welt reports Saturday, in an advance
release of an article to be published Sunday.
Suggestions targeting a
fiscal, banking, and political union, as well as structural reforms,
are being worked out by E.U. Council President Herman van Rompuy,
E.U. Commission chief Jose Manuel Barroso, Eurogroup Chairman
Jean-Claude Juncker and European Central Bank President Mario Draghi,
according to the article. The plan is to be presented at a summit of
European leaders at end of June, the article says."
Less
than credible sources report that Spiderman towels (which are now
trading at negative repo rates) and cross-rehypothecated kitchen
sinks are also key components of all future "master
plans"
which sadly are absolutely meaningless since the signature of
Europe's paymaster - the Bundesrepublik - is as usual lacking. Which
is why, "the plan may well mean that the euro zone adopts
measures not immediately accepted by the whole of the European Union,
the article adds." So... European sub-union? Hardly strange is
that just as this latest desperate attempt at distraction from the
complete chaos in Europe (which will only find a resolution once XO
crosses 1000 as we and Citi
suggested two
weeks ago and when the world is truly on the verge of the
abyss), none
other than George Soros has just started a 3-month countdown to
European the European D(oom)-Day.
Germany and its central bank are unlikely to lead the way out of the euro zone debt crisis within three months time, after which it will be too late, U.S. billionaire George Soros said on Saturday.
Speaking at an economic conference in Trento, Italy, Soros said that the euro crisis - which he defined as a sovereign debt crisis and a banking crisis closely interlinked - threatened to destroy the European Union and plunge it into a lost decade like Latin America in the 1980s.
Soros said he expected Greek elections in June to produce a government willing to stick by the current bailout agreements, but which would find it impossible to do so.
We
disagree: the next Greek elections will be merely a rerun of the
first - lots of sound and fury, signifying no government, as the
country becomes the next Belgium (as we noted here before
the outcome of
the first election was even known), ends up an anarchy state, without
a government, as what little money the Treasury has goes to pay
English-law bondholders, until finally there is nothing left. But
that is neither here nor there, because at this point it is not about
Greece any more:
"The Greek crisis is liable to come to a climax in the fall. By that time the German economy will also be weakening so that Chancellor (Angela) Merkel will find it even more difficult than today to persuade the German public to accept any additional European responsibilities. That is what creates a three-month window," he said.
The Hungarian-born U.S. financier said that all the "blame and burden" of adjusting the euro area's imbalances was falling on weaker peripheral countries, but the bloc's core bore an ever greater responsibility for the crisis.
"The 'centre' is responsible for designing a flawed system, enacting flawed treaties, pursuing flawed policies and always doing too little too late," he said.
The
flights of fancy continue,
Soros urged creating a European deposit insurance scheme and called for direct bank access to the euro zone's rescue fund, as well as for joint financial supervision and regulation.
Yes
and if wishes were horses... because even Goldman Sachs and Barclays
said a European deposit fund is wonderful in theory, but in practice
won't be coming for a long time (as further explained
why here and here),
if at all:
1
. Operational difficulties
- What currency are claimants paid in?
- If they are paid in the new currency, how is the loss rate established?
- How would capital controls impact settlement?
2.
Size of the potential redenomination loss
- The redenomination loss would be greater than typical losses in FDIC insured bank failures
- Potential losses are large enough to call the credibility of the guarantee into question
3.
Moral hazard problems
- This type of guarantee scheme would make it less painful for peripheral European nations to leave the eurozone
- Under a euro-value guarantee, a country could exit, massively reducing sovereign liabilities, while maintaining a substantial amount of household savings value
4.
Finally, a euro-value guarantee scheme would be a massive contingent
liability for guarantors that
only pays out after a member exit --not an ideal setup
Soros
vision of utopia continues:
The euro zone would eventually need a financial authority that could take over much of individual countries' solvency risk.
Soros said that the financial system in Europe was fragmenting and reorganising itself along national lines, which in a few years time may make an orderly euro break up possible.
But "an earlier breakup is bound to be disorderly," almost certainly leading to a collapse of the EU itself, he said.
He said it would take German authorities "an extraordinary effort" to gather public support in the coming three months for the measures which are needed to halt current trends.
"We need to do whatever we can to convince Germany to show leadership and preserve the European Union as the fantastic object that it used to be," he said.
There
is one problem with all of this: for the decade or so that the EMU
worked, Germany was the sole true beneficiary. What the world is in
effect asking Germany is to unwind the years of having outsmarted
everyone else, and to redistribute the benefits to all the others who
were dumb enough not to get what was going on. And as a reminder,
Germany said, okalie dokalie: just first pledge your gold to Herr
Pawn Shop operator in case you still go broke after we bail you out.
So
far it has been everyone else in Europe, those who demand to be
bailed out that is, that has been rather mum on this response from
Germany.
But
yes, let's blame it on all Germany for daring to have benefitted from
outsmarting others.
In
short: Soros
is right about one thing - 3 months. And Counting.
Remarks
at the Festival of Economics, Trento Italy
Ever
since the Crash of 2008 there has been a widespread recognition, both
among economists and the general public, that economic theory has
failed. But there is no consensus on the causes and the extent of
that failure.
I
believe that the failure is more profound than generally recognized.
It goes back to the foundations of economic theory. Economics tried
to model itself on Newtonian physics. It sought to establish
universally and timelessly valid laws governing reality. But
economics is a social science and there is a fundamental difference
between the natural and social sciences. Social phenomena have
thinking participants who base their decisions on imperfect
knowledge. That is what economic theory has tried to ignore.
Scientific
method needs an independent criterion, by which the truth or validity
of its theories can be judged. Natural phenomena constitute such a
criterion; social phenomena do not. That is because natural phenomena
consist of facts that unfold independently of any statements that
relate to them. The facts then serve as objective evidence by which
the validity of scientific theories can be judged. That has enabled
natural science to produce amazing results.
Social
events, by contrast, have thinking participants who have a will of
their own. They are not detached observers but engaged decision
makers whose decisions greatly influence the course of events.
Therefore the events do not constitute an independent criterion by
which participants can decide whether their views are valid. In the
absence of an independent criterion people have to base their
decisions not on knowledge but on an inherently biased and to greater
or lesser extent distorted interpretation of reality. Their lack of
perfect knowledge or fallibility introduces an element of
indeterminacy into the course of events that is absent when the
events relate to the behavior of inanimate objects. The resulting
uncertainty hinders the social sciences in producing laws similar to
Newton’s physics.
Economics,
which became the most influential of the social sciences, sought to
remove this handicap by taking an axiomatic approach similar to
Euclid’s geometry. But Euclid’s axioms closely resembled reality
while the theory of rational expectations and the efficient market
hypothesis became far removed from it. Up to a point the axiomatic
approach worked. For instance, the theory of perfect competition
postulated perfect knowledge. But the postulate worked only as long
as it was applied to the exchange of physical goods. When it came to
production, as distinct from exchange, or to the use of money and
credit, the postulate became untenable because the participants’
decisions involved the future and the future cannot be known until it
has actually occurred.
I
am not well qualified to criticize the theory of rational
expectations and the efficient market hypothesis because as a market
participant I considered them so unrealistic that I never bothered to
study them. That is an indictment in itself but I shall leave a
detailed critique of these theories to others.
Instead,
I should like to put before you a radically different approach to
financial markets. It was inspired by Karl Popper who taught me that
people’s interpretation of reality never quite corresponds to
reality itself. This led me to study the relationship between the
two. I found a two-way connection between the participants’
thinking and the situations in which they participate. On the one
hand people seek to understand the situation; that is the cognitive
function. On the other, they seek to make an impact on the situation;
I call that the causative or manipulative function. The two functions
connect the thinking agents and the situations in which they
participate in opposite directions. In the cognitive function the
situation is supposed to determine the participants’ views; in the
causative function the participants’ views are supposed to
determine the outcome. When both functions are at work at the same
time they interfere with each other. The two functions form a
circular relationship or feedback loop. I call that feedback loop
reflexivity. In a reflexive situation the participants’ views
cannot correspond to reality because reality is not something
independently given; it is contingent on the participants’ views
and decisions. The decisions, in turn, cannot be based on knowledge
alone; they must contain some bias or guess work about the future
because the future is contingent on the participants’ decisions.
Fallibility
and reflexivity are tied together like Siamese twins. Without
fallibility there would be no reflexivity – although the opposite
is not the case: people’s understanding would be imperfect even in
the absence of reflexivity. Of the two twins, fallibility is the
first born. Together, they ensure both a divergence between the
participants’ view of reality and the actual state of affairs and a
divergence between the participants’ expectations and the actual
outcome.
Obviously,
I did not discover reflexivity. Others had recognized it before me,
often under a different name. Robert Merton wrote about
self-fulfilling prophecies and the bandwagon effect, Keynes compared
financial markets to a beauty contest where the participants had to
guess who would be the most popular choice. But starting from
fallibility and reflexivity I focused on a problem area, namely the
role of misconceptions and misunderstandings in shaping the course of
events that mainstream economics tried to ignore. This has made my
interpretation of reality more realistic than the prevailing
paradigm.
Among
other things, I developed a model of a boom-bust process or bubble
which is endogenous to financial markets, not the result of external
shocks. According to my theory, financial bubbles are not a purely
psychological phenomenon. They have two components: a trend
that prevails in reality and a misinterpretation of that trend. A
bubble can develop when the feedback is initially positive in the
sense that both the trend and its biased interpretation are mutually
reinforced. Eventually the gap between the trend and its biased
interpretation grows so wide that it becomes unsustainable.
After a
twilight period both the bias and the trend are reversed and
reinforce each other in the opposite direction. Bubbles are usually
asymmetric in shape: booms develop slowly but the bust tends to be
sudden and devastating. That is due to the use of leverage: price
declines precipitate the forced liquidation of leveraged positions.
Well-formed
financial bubbles always follow this pattern but the magnitude and
duration of each phase is unpredictable. Moreover the process can be
aborted at any stage so that well-formed financial bubbles occur
rather infrequently.
At
any moment of time there are myriads of feedback loops at work, some
of which are positive, others negative. They interact with each
other, producing the irregular price patterns that prevail most of
the time; but on the rare occasions that bubbles develop to their
full potential they tend to overshadow all other influences.
According
to my theory financial markets may just as soon produce bubbles as
tend toward equilibrium. Since bubbles disrupt financial markets,
history has been punctuated by financial crises. Each crisis provoked
a regulatory response. That is how central banking and financial
regulations have evolved, in step with the markets themselves.
Bubbles occur only intermittently but the interplay between markets
and regulators is ongoing. Since both market participants and
regulators act on the basis of imperfect knowledge the interplay
between them is reflexive. Moreover reflexivity and fallibility are
not confined to the financial markets; they also characterize other
spheres of social life, particularly politics. Indeed, in light of
the ongoing interaction between markets and regulators it is quite
misleading to study financial markets in isolation. Behind the
invisible hand of the market lies the visible hand of politics.
Instead of pursuing timeless laws and models we ought to study events
in their time bound context.
My
interpretation of financial markets differs from the prevailing
paradigm in many ways. I emphasize the role of misunderstandings and
misconceptions in shaping the course of history. And I treat bubbles
as largely unpredictable. The direction and its eventual reversal are
predictable; the magnitude and duration of the various phases is not.
I contend that taking fallibility as the starting point makes my
conceptual framework more realistic. But at a price: the idea that
laws or models of universal validity can predict the future must be
abandoned.
Until
recently, my interpretation of financial markets was either ignored
or dismissed by academic economists. All this has changed since the
crash of 2008. Reflexivity became recognized but, with the exception
of Imperfect Knowledge Economics, the foundations of economic theory
have not been subjected to the profound rethinking that I consider
necessary. Reflexivity has been accommodated by speaking of multiple
equilibria instead of a single one. But that is not enough. The
fallibility of market participants, regulators, and economists must
also be recognized. A truly dynamic situation cannot be
understood by studying multiple equilibria. We need to study
the process of change.
The
euro crisis is particularly instructive in this regard. It
demonstrates the role of misconceptions and a lack of understanding
in shaping the course of history. The authorities didn’t understand
the nature of the euro crisis; they thought it is a fiscal problem
while it is more of a banking problem and a problem of
competitiveness. And they applied the wrong remedy: you cannot reduce
the debt burden by shrinking the economy, only by growing your way
out of it. The crisis is still growing because of a failure to
understand the dynamics of social change; policy measures that could
have worked at one point in time were no longer sufficient by the
time they were applied.
Since
the euro crisis is currently exerting an overwhelming influence on
the global economy I shall devote the rest of my talk to it. I must
start with a warning: the discussion will take us beyond the confines
of economic theory into politics and the dynamics of social change.
But my conceptual framework based on the twin pillars of fallibility
and reflexivity still applies. Reflexivity doesn’t always manifest
itself in the form of bubbles. The reflexive interplay between
imperfect markets and imperfect authorities goes on all the time
while bubbles occur only infrequently. This is a rare occasion when
the interaction exerts such a large influence that it casts its
shadow on the global economy. How could this happen? My answer is
that there is a bubble involved, after all, but it is not a financial
but a political one. It relates to the political evolution of the
European Union and it has led me to the conclusion that the euro
crisis threatens to destroy the European Union. Let me explain.
I
contend that the European Union itself is like a bubble. In the boom
phase the EU was what the psychoanalyst David Tuckett calls a
“fantastic object” – unreal but immensely attractive. The EU
was the embodiment of an open society –an association of nations
founded on the principles of democracy, human rights, and rule of law
in which no nation or nationality would have a dominant position.
The
process of integration was spearheaded by a small group of far
sighted statesmen who practiced what Karl Popper called piecemeal
social engineering. They recognized that perfection is unattainable;
so they set limited objectives and firm timelines and then mobilized
the political will for a small step forward, knowing full well that
when they achieved it, its inadequacy would become apparent and
require a further step. The process fed on its own success, very much
like a financial bubble. That is how the Coal and Steel Community was
gradually transformed into the European Union, step by step.
Germany
used to be in the forefront of the effort. When the Soviet empire
started to disintegrate, Germany’s leaders realized that
reunification was possible only in the context of a more united
Europe and they were willing to make considerable sacrifices to
achieve it. When it came to bargaining they were willing to
contribute a little more and take a little less than the others,
thereby facilitating agreement. At that time, German statesmen
used to assert that Germany has no independent foreign policy, only a
European one.
The
process culminated with the Maastricht Treaty and the introduction of
the euro. It was followed by a period of stagnation which, after the
crash of 2008, turned into a process of disintegration. The first
step was taken by Germany when, after the bankruptcy of Lehman
Brothers, Angela Merkel declared that the virtual guarantee extended
to other financial institutions should come from each country acting
separately, not by Europe acting jointly. It took financial markets
more than a year to realize the implication of that declaration,
showing that they are not perfect.
The
Maastricht Treaty was fundamentally flawed, demonstrating the
fallibility of the authorities. Its main weakness was well known to
its architects: it established a monetary union without a political
union. The architects believed however, that when the need arose the
political will could be generated to take the necessary steps towards
a political union.
But
the euro also had some other defects of which the architects were
unaware and which are not fully understood even today. In retrospect
it is now clear that the main source of trouble is that the member
states of the euro have surrendered to the European Central Bank
their rights to create fiat money. They did not realize what that
entails – and neither did the European authorities. When the euro
was introduced the regulators allowed banks to buy unlimited amounts
of government bonds without setting aside any equity capital; and the
central bank accepted all government bonds at its discount window on
equal terms. Commercial banks found it advantageous to accumulate the
bonds of the weaker euro members in order to earn a few extra basis
points. That is what caused interest rates to converge which in turn
caused
competitiveness to diverge. Germany, struggling with the
burdens of reunification, undertook structural reforms and became
more competitive. Other countries enjoyed housing and consumption
booms on the back of cheap credit, making them less competitive. Then
came the crash of 2008 which created conditions that were far removed
from those prescribed by the Maastricht Treaty. Many governments had
to shift bank liabilities on to their own balance sheets and engage
in massive deficit spending. These countries found themselves in the
position of a third world country that had become heavily indebted in
a currency that it did not control. Due to the divergence in economic
performance Europe became divided between creditor and debtor
countries. This is having far reaching political implications to
which I will revert.
It
took some time for the financial markets to discover that government
bonds which had been considered riskless are subject to speculative
attack and may actually default; but when they did, risk premiums
rose dramatically. This rendered commercial banks whose balance
sheets were loaded with those bonds potentially insolvent. And that
constituted the two main components of the problem confronting us
today: a sovereign debt crisis and a banking crisis which are closely
interlinked.
The
eurozone is now repeating what had often happened in the global
financial system. There is a close parallel between the euro crisis
and the international banking crisis that erupted in 1982. Then the
international financial authorities did whatever was necessary to
protect the banking system: they inflicted hardship on the periphery
in order to protect the center. Now Germany and the other creditor
countries are unknowingly playing the same role. The details differ
but the idea is the same: the creditors are in effect shifting the
burden of adjustment on to the debtor countries and avoiding their
own responsibility for the imbalances. Interestingly, the terms
“center” and “periphery” have crept into usage almost
unnoticed. Just as in the 1980’s all the blame and burden is
falling on the “periphery” and the responsibility of the “center”
has never been properly acknowledged. Yet in the euro crisis
the responsibility of the center is even greater than it was in 1982.
The “center” is responsible for designing a flawed system,
enacting flawed treaties, pursuing flawed policies and always doing
too little too late. In the 1980’s Latin America suffered a lost
decade; a similar fate now awaits Europe. That is the responsibility
that Germany and the other creditor countries need to acknowledge.
But there is now sign of this happening.
The
European authorities had little understanding of what was happening.
They were prepared to deal with fiscal problems but only Greece
qualified as a fiscal crisis; the rest of Europe suffered from a
banking crisis and a divergence in competitiveness which gave rise to
a balance of payments crisis. The authorities did not even understand
the nature of the problem, let alone see a solution. So they tried to
buy time.
Usually
that works. Financial panics subside and the authorities realize a
profit on their intervention. But not this time because the financial
problems were reinforced by a process of political disintegration.
While the European Union was being created, the leadership was in the
forefront of further integration; but after the outbreak of the
financial crisis the authorities became wedded to preserving the
status quo. This has forced all those who consider the status quo
unsustainable or intolerable into an anti-European posture. That is
the political dynamic that makes the disintegration of the European
Union just as self-reinforcing as its creation has been. That
is the political bubble I was talking about.
At
the onset of the crisis a breakup of the euro was inconceivable: the
assets and liabilities denominated in a common currency were so
intermingled that a breakup would have led to an uncontrollable
meltdown. But as the crisis progressed the financial system has been
progressively reordered along national lines. This trend has gathered
momentum in recent months. The Long Term Refinancing Operation (LTRO)
undertaken by the European Central Bank enabled Spanish and Italian
banks to engage in a very profitable and low risk arbitrage by buying
the bonds of their own countries. And other investors have been
actively divesting themselves of the sovereign debt of the periphery
countries.
If
this continued for a few more years a break-up of the euro would
become possible without a meltdown – the omelet could be
unscrambled – but it would leave the central banks of the creditor
countries with large claims against the central banks of the debtor
countries which would be difficult to collect. This is due to an
arcane problem in the euro clearing system called Target2. In
contrast to the clearing system of the Federal Reserve, which is
settled annually, Target2 accumulates the imbalances. This did not
create a problem as long as the interbank system was functioning
because the banks settled the imbalances themselves through the
interbank market. But the interbank market has not functioned
properly since 2007 and the banks relied increasingly on the Target
system. And since the summer of 2011 there has been increasing
capital flight from the weaker countries. So the imbalances grew
exponentially. By the end of March this year the Bundesbank had
claims of some 660 billion euros against the central banks of the
periphery countries.
The
Bundesbank has become aware of the potential danger. It is now
engaged in a campaign against the indefinite expansion of the money
supply and it has started taking measures to limit the losses it
would sustain in case of a breakup. This is creating a
self-fulfilling prophecy. Once the Bundesbank starts guarding against
a breakup everybody will have to do the same.
This
is already happening. Financial institutions are increasingly
reordering their European exposure along national lines just in case
the region splits apart. Banks give preference to shedding assets
outside their national borders and risk managers try to match assets
and liabilities within national borders rather than within the
eurozone as a whole. The indirect effect of this asset-liability
matching is to reinforce the deleveraging process and to reduce the
availability of credit, particularly to the small and medium
enterprises which are the main source of employment.
So
the crisis is getting ever deeper. Tensions in financial markets have
risen to new highs as shown by the historic low yield on Bunds. Even
more telling is the fact that the yield on British 10 year bonds has
never been lower in its 300 year history while the risk premium on
Spanish bonds is at a new high.
The
real economy of the eurozone is declining while Germany is still
booming. This means that the divergence is getting wider. The
political and social dynamics are also working toward disintegration.
Public opinion as expressed in recent election results is
increasingly opposed to austerity and this trend is likely to grow
until the policy is reversed. So something has to give.
In
my judgment the authorities have a three months’ window during
which they could still correct their mistakes and reverse the current
trends. By the authorities I mean mainly the German government and
the Bundesbank because in a crisis the creditors are in the driver’s
seat and nothing can be done without German support.
I
expect that the Greek public will be sufficiently frightened by the
prospect of expulsion from the European Union that it will give a
narrow majority of seats to a coalition that is ready to abide by the
current agreement. But no government can meet the conditions so that
the Greek crisis is liable to come to a climax in the fall. By that
time the German economy will also be weakening so that Chancellor
Merkel will find it even more difficult than today to persuade the
German public to accept any additional European responsibilities.
That is what creates a three months’ window.
Correcting
the mistakes and reversing the trend would require some extraordinary
policy measures to bring conditions back closer to normal, and bring
relief to the financial markets and the banking system. These
measures must, however, conform to the existing treaties. The
treaties could then be revised in a calmer atmosphere so that the
current imbalances will not recur. It is difficult but not impossible
to design some extraordinary measures that would meet these tough
requirements. They would have to tackle simultaneously the banking
problem and the problem of excessive government debt, because these
problems are interlinked. Addressing one without the other, as in the
past, will not work.
Banks
need a European deposit insurance scheme in order to stem the capital
flight. They also need direct financing by the European Stability
Mechanism (ESM) which has to go hand-in-hand with eurozone-wide
supervision and regulation. The heavily indebted countries need
relief on their financing costs. There are various ways to provide it
but they all need the active support of the Bundesbank and the German
government.
That
is where the blockage is. The authorities are working feverishly to
come up with a set of proposals in time for the European summit at
the end of this month. Based on the current newspaper reports the
measures they will propose will cover all the bases I mentioned but
they will offer only the minimum on which the various parties can
agree while what is needed is a convincing commitment to reverse the
trend. That means the measures will again offer some temporary relief
but the trends will continue. But we are at an inflection point.
After the expiration of the three months’ window the markets will
continue to demand more but the authorities will not be able to meet
their demands.
It
is impossible to predict the eventual outcome. As mentioned before,
the gradual reordering of the financial system along national lines
could make an orderly breakup of the euro possible in a few years’
time and, if it were not for the social and political dynamics, one
could imagine a common market without a common currency. But the
trends are clearly non-linear and an earlier breakup is bound to be
disorderly. It would almost certainly lead to a collapse of the
Schengen Treaty, the common market, and the European Union itself.
(It should be remembered that there is an exit mechanism for the
European Union but not for the euro.) Unenforceable claims and
unsettled grievances would leave Europe worse off than it was at the
outset when the project of a united Europe was conceived.
But
the likelihood is that the euro will survive because a breakup would
be devastating not only for the periphery but also for Germany. It
would leave Germany with large unenforceable claims against the
periphery countries. The Bundesbank alone will have over a trillion
euros of claims arising out of Target2 by the end of this year, in
addition to all the intergovernmental obligations. And a return to
the Deutschemark would likely price Germany out of its export markets
– not to mention the political consequences. So Germany is likely
to do what is necessary to preserve the euro – but nothing more.
That would result in a eurozone dominated by Germany in which the
divergence between the creditor and debtor countries would continue
to widen and the periphery would turn into permanently depressed
areas in need of constant transfer of payments. That would turn the
European Union into something very different from what it was when it
was a “fantastic object” that fired peoples imagination. It would
be a German empire with the periphery as the hinterland.
I
believe most of us would find that objectionable but I have a great
deal of sympathy with Germany in its present predicament. The German
public cannot understand why a policy of structural reforms and
fiscal austerity that worked for Germany a decade ago will not work
Europe today. Germany then could enjoy an export led recovery but the
eurozone today is caught in a deflationary debt trap. The German
public does not see any deflation at home; on the contrary, wages are
rising and there are vacancies for skilled jobs which are eagerly
snapped up by immigrants from other European countries. Reluctance to
invest abroad and the influx of flight capital are fueling a real
estate boom. Exports may be slowing but employment is still rising.
In these circumstances it would require an extraordinary effort by
the German government to convince the German public to embrace the
extraordinary measures that would be necessary to reverse the current
trend. And they have only a three months’ window in which to do it.
We
need to do whatever we can to convince Germany to show leadership and
preserve the European Union as the fantastic object that it used to
be. The future of Europe depends on it.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.